The simple arithmetic of carbon pricing and stranded assets
Abstract
A simple rule for the optimal global price of carbon is presented, which captures the geophysical, economic, and ethical drivers of climate policy as well as the effect of uncertainty about future growth of consumption. There is also a discussion of the optimal carbon budget and the amount of unburnable carbon and stranded fossil fuel reserves and a back-on-the-envelope expression are given for calculating these. It is also shown how one can derive the end of the carbon era and peak warming. This simple arithmetic for determining climate policy is meant to complement the simulations of large-scale integrated assessment model, and to give analytical understanding of the key determinants of climate policy. The simple rules perform very well in a full integrated assessment model. It is also shown how to take account of a 2 °C upper limit on global warming. Steady increases in energy efficiency do not affect the optimal price of carbon, but postpone the carbon-free era somewhat and if technical progress in renewables and economic growth are strong leads to substantially lower cumulative emissions and lower peak global warming.
Keywords
Social cost of carbon Carbon budget Peak warming End of carbon eraJEL codes
H21 Q51 Q54Introduction
Climate change is the world largest externality (Stern 2007) and climate policy needs to correct this externality by establishing cost transparency in the energy market. Fossil fuels are currently too cheap, since users of this energy type are not shouldering the cost of future climate damages and renewable energy is still in its infancy. The introduction of a carbon tax (or a cap on overall emissions levels) will shift demand in the global energy system away from dirty towards carbon-free energy sources. It will also increase the cost of energy overall, at least in the short run while efficiency improvements in the renewable energy sector are still ongoing, making investments in energy demand reductions more attractive. Here we present the arithmetic underlying carbon pricing and show how to calculate in a simple way the optimal timing of the transition to the carbon-free era and the amount of cumulative carbon emissions and peak global warming. Our rule for the carbon price is simple but robust and can be useful for analysing the effects of carbon pricing on patterns of energy generation and energy use.
Climate policy has to combine ethical judgments with projections about future economic, technological, and climatic developments. Integrated assessment models (IAMs) aim to do this, but have been criticised for being highly complex, insufficiently open access, and underestimating the threats of climate change (Stern 2016). We present a simple framework that captures the essence of IAMs, makes their underlying assumptions transparent, and opens the discussion of the political and social obstacles to climate policy. Our cost-benefit analysis of climate action yields a simple rule for the optimal global price of carbon in the presence of a backstop renewable energy source that is currently more expensive than fossil fuel. This price is proportional to current world GDP and depends on key ethical considerations, damage flows and geophysical parameters. We also offer rules for the optimal fraction of fossil fuel reserves that should be left in the crust of the earth (cf. Carbon Tracker 2013; McGlade and Ekins 2015) and the optimal transition time to the carbon-free era. Our calculations require only a pencil and the back of an envelope, but yield values very close to those obtained from numerically maximising welfare with a detailed IAM of growth, development, energy, and climate change. We hope that our simple arithmetic helps policy makers and climate scientists to gain a better understanding of the ethical, economic, and geophysical drivers of optimal climate policy.1
The outlay of the paper is as follows. The “The carbon cycle and the cost of emitting carbon” section discusses the multi-box carbon cycle and the cost of emitting carbon, the “Intergenerational ethics and the risk-adjusted discount rate” section discusses the intergenerational ethics and the risk-adjusted discount rate, the “Simple rule for the global price of carbon” section presents our simple rule for the optimal price of carbon, the “The energy transition, the carbon budget, and stranded fossil fuel reserves” section derives the optimal carbon budget and the amount of stranded fossil fuel reserves, and the “End of carbon era and peak warming” section shows how to calculate the onset of the carbon-free era and peak warming and derives the effects of energy efficiency. The “Putting it together” section puts it all together, and the “Calibration and illustrative policy simulations” section offers a calibration and illustrates our analysis with some simulations. The “Implementing the 2 °C target” section shows how to take account of a 2 °C upper limit on global warming. The “Performance of the simple rules” section shows how well our simple arithmetic of climate policy performs in a full integrated assessment model. The “Carbon capture and sequestration as backstop” section discusses carbon capture and sequestration. The “Conclusion” section concludes.
The carbon cycle and the cost of emitting carbon
The global price of emitting carbon, P, should generally be set to the social cost of carbon, which is the present discounted value of all future economic damages from emitting one ton of carbon today. This price can be levied via either a carbon tax or an emissions permit. To compute future economic damages, we allow for n different parts of the atmospheric carbon stock each one of them decaying at a different rate. This leads to a so-called n-box model of the carbon cycle. With the fraction ai of each emitted ton entering a box i with exponential decay rate bi, the amount left in the atmosphere after t years equals \( {\sum}_{i=1}^n{a}_i{\left(1-{b}_i\right)}^t \). The easiest is to have a two-box carbon cycle (i.e. n = 2) with the first box consisting of the permanent component of atmospheric carbon which corresponds to the 20% of carbon emissions stays up for thousands of years in the atmosphere (a1 = 0.2, b1 = 0) and a second box consisting of the transient component of atmospheric carbon (a2 = 0.32 and b2 = 0.0023). Such a simple modelling of the carbon cycle captures well the carbon cycle of the most prominent IAM, i.e. DICE set out in Nordhaus (2008) (Golosov et al. 2014).2
Next, we assume that the flow damage at time t of an extra ton of atmospheric carbon is proportional to world GDP, i.e. d GDPt, where d is estimated to be 5.3% of GDP at roughly 2 °C based on DICE and does not vary much with temperature (Golosov et al. 2014).3 It takes a long time before changes in the stock of atmospheric carbon affect global mean temperature and cause damages to aggregate production. We model this by allowing for a simple exponential lag between projected global mean temperature and the damages that result from that on the one hand and the stock of atmospheric carbon of l years on the other hand. We denote the mean of this exponential lag by the parameter l. In our baseline calibration, we take this mean lag l to be 70 years.
Intergenerational ethics and the risk-adjusted discount rate
Simple rule for the global price of carbon
This rule offers the following insights into the drivers of climate policy. First, the optimal global price of carbon is proportional to and rises with world GDP, about 66 trillion US dollars in 2010, and to the flow cost of global warming per ton of emitted carbon, d. Second, the global carbon price is high if the SDR is low, which from (1) is the case if welfare of future generations is not discounted much (low RTI) and, given trend GDP growth, intergenerational inequality aversion is weak (low IIA). Third, if IIA > 1, the ethical positive effect of higher trend growth (higher g) on the SDR via richer future generations dominates the negative effect on SDR − g due to faster growing damages of global warming. This depresses the optimal price of carbon. In contrast, more uncertainty about future consumption growth, especially if risk aversion is substantial (high RRA), curbs the growth-corrected discount rate and boosts the price of carbon. Fourth, lower decay rates of atmospheric carbon (higher bi) and a shorter temperature lag (low l) increase the carbon price due to longer-lasting and more immediate damages. Energy efficiency does not impact the optimal price of carbon.
The energy transition, the carbon budget, and stranded fossil fuel reserves
The carbon budget is low if fossil fuel is expensive to extract and if renewable energy is cheap to produce (high E0 and low R0). The carbon budget is curbed by the ethical, economic, and geophysical factors that drive up the price of carbon (high SDR − g or high Ω from (1) and (2), high d and high GDP0). If fossil fuel extraction is expected to experience rapid directed technical progress, the optimal carbon budget will be higher. If renewable energy is expected to experience rapid technical progress (as is the case now for solar energy), the optimal carbon budget ends up lower as climate policy has become cheaper. The fraction of stranded fossil fuel assets, S(T)/S0 = (S0 − B)/S0, is then high.
End of carbon era and peak warming
Generally, more energy-efficient technologies are described in a stylised fashion as using higher capital and less energy inputs. Such technologies arise when less fossil fuel energy inputs are used in favour of more capital in response to, say, a tax on the use of fossil fuel. However, empirical evidence suggests that there is limited substitutability between energy and capital and labour (Hassler et al. 2012) in which case fossil fuel use is proportional to aggregate output. More specifically, fossil fuel use is given by γ0(1 − rγ)tGDPt where the initial energy intensity γ0 is calibrated at 0.15 GtC per trillion dollars of world GDP (cf. Rezai and van der Ploeg 2016). There might be a negative exponential trend in the energy intensity or carbon intensities of output at the rate rγ ≥ 0. If rγ > 0, then the energy efficiency of the world economy increases over time. A different way of looking at this is that renewable energies and fossil fuel energies are bad substitutes as long as the problem of storage is not solved in a cost-efficient manner. More efficient-energy technologies can then be seen as those which use more renewable and less fossil fuel energies.
The transition thus occurs more quickly if the carbon budget B is small, expected economic growth g is high, and the rate of increase in energy efficiency rγ is small. To analyse the effect of increases in energy efficiency, we first note from (1) that this does not affect the optimal price of carbon. We note from (4) that both a higher carbon budget B and a higher energy efficiency leads to a longer fossil fuel phase T. Equation (3) indicates that cumulative emissions decrease with the length of the fossil fuel phase T. The reason is that, if the time of the switch to the carbon-free era takes place later, technical progress in the renewable energies industry has led to a lower cost of renewables and economic growth has led to a higher cost of carbon. Assuming that these outweigh the effect of technical progress on costs in the fossil fuel industry, we see that higher T must be associated with lower fossil fuel extraction cost and thus a lower cumulative extraction B. Combining the comparative statics of Eqs. (3) and (4), we thus deduce that higher energy efficiency or a rising trend in energy efficiency leads to lower cumulative emissions and a longer fossil fuel phase (lower B, higher T).
Although a linear approximation to (5) works reasonably well (Allen 2016), we use a quadratic which is slightly more accurate.6 The carbon budget from pre-industrial times onwards corresponding to a maximum of 2 °C is 1 TtC, implying a carbon budget for cumulative emissions of 350 GtC or 1283 GtCO2 from 2010 onwards.
Putting it together
From (2), we know that a smaller SDR (due to more patience, less intergenerational inequality aversion and, if IIA > 1, lower trend GDP growth and more risk aversion), a lower decay rate, and a shorter temperature lag push up the carbon price and shift up the upward-sloping solid climate policy line in the top panel of Fig. 1. Renewable energy then becomes competitive earlier when energy cost is relatively higher, leaving a bigger fraction of fossil fuel reserves stranded, and cutting cumulative emissions and peak warming.
If the coefficient of intergenerational inequality aversion exceeds unity (IIA > 1), faster trend GDP growth makes future generations richer and decreases the ethical onus on current generations to curb emissions, especially if IIA is high, so the SDR rises and climate policy becomes less ambitious and temperature rises. A lower and falling cost of renewable energy shifts down the cost curve in the top panel (the downward-sloping solid line), which curbs the carbon budget, brings forward the carbon-free era and cuts peak warming. The energy cost at the time of transition is now relatively lower.
Calibration and illustrative policy simulations
Baseline calibration of the back-on-the-envelope IAM
Ethical |
Rate of time impatience: RTI = 1.5%/year Relative intergenerational inequality aversion and risk aversion: IIA = RRA = 1.45 |
Economic |
World economy: GDP0 = 66 T$, rate of growth: g = 2%/year, volatility: σ = 0.036, Fossil fuel use per unit of world GDP: γ0 = 0.15 GtC/T$, rate of decline: rγ = 0%/year Fossil fuel cost: E0 = 0.35 T$/GtC, rE = 0, e1 = 0.5, Renewable energy cost: R0 = 0.8 T$/GtC, rate of decline: rR = 1%/year Flow damage as fraction of world GDP: d = 0.053 $/tC |
Geophysical |
Initial stock of fossil fuel reserves: S0 = 10,000 GtC Coefficients permanent and transient box of carbon cycle: a1 = 0.2, b1 = 0, a2 = 0.32, b2 = 0.0023 Average lag between temperature/damages and carbon stock: l = 70 years Transient climate response to cumulative emissions: TCRE = 2 °C/TtC |
Sensitivity of peak warming and carbon budget to ethical and economic drivers
Scenario | PW (°C) | Carbon budget (GtC) |
---|---|---|
Baseline | 2.8 | 1046 |
Ethical | ||
Lower inequality aversion (IIA = 0.5) | 1.8 | 264 |
Lower discount rate (RTI = 0%/year) | 2.1 | 465 |
Economic | ||
Lower economic growth rate (g = 1%/year) | 2.6 | 836 |
High Damage scenario (d = 0.08) | 2.6 | 885 |
Lower initial cost of renewable energy (R0 = 0.64 $T/GtC) | 2.3 | 642 |
Lower initial cost of fossil energy (E0 = 0.28 $T/GtC) | 3.2 | 1419 |
Faster reductions in cost of renewable energy (rr = 2%/year) | 2.1 | 474 |
If global economic growth slows from 2 to 1% per annum, future material affluence will be lower and the initial carbon price rises in order to shield future generations from climate-related damages to their weakened economy. Peak warming declines to 2.6 °C corresponding to a fall of the carbon budget to 836 GtC. Higher vulnerability of the economy to climate change in the form of higher damages has a similar effect on peak warming and the carbon budget. A 20% reduction in today’s cost of renewable (fossil) energy significantly expedites (delays) the transition to the carbon-free era and decreases (increases) peak warming to 2.3 °C (3.2 °C) and the carbon budget to 642 GtC (1419 GtC). An acceleration of directed technical change in the renewable sector from 1 to 2% per annum brings forward the energy transition and cuts peak warming to 2.1 °C and the carbon budget to 473 GtC. The model can be used to calculate the impacts of shifts in the geophysical components in a similar fashion.
Peak warming can be lowered by moving to the upper-left corner: lower preparedness to sacrifice utility to cut future global warming (higher IIA) requires more technical progress (higher rR) through policies stimulating innovation and R&D. Both panels illustrate how big the challenge and how ambitious policies must be to stay well below 2 °C peak warming as agreed in Paris.
Finally, let us now perform a sensitivity exercise where the rate of increase in energy efficiency is 1.5 or 1% instead of zero per year (i.e. rγ = 0.015/year or 0.01/year). The price of carbon is unaffected. From Eqs. (3) and (4), we can calculate that the safe carbon budget drops from 1046 GtC in the benchmark to 674 or 856 GtC and that the transition to the carbon-free era then takes only a little longer, 58 or 57 years, respectively, instead of 56 years.
Implementing the 2 °C target
An alternative to adjusting damages from global warming upwards to ensure that peak warming does not exceed 2 °C is to abstract from damages entirely and simply minimise the present discounted value of costs subject to the constraint that peak warming must not exceed 2 °C. This is what is done in the integrated assessment literature and the resulting price of carbon follows a Hotelling path and thus rises more rapidly at a rate equal to the rate of interest instead of the rate of economic growth (e.g. Nordhaus 1982; Tol 2013; Bauer et al. 2015). The more rapidly rising price of carbon then reflects the increasing scarcity of carbon as the carbon budget approaches exhaustion. However, if allowance is made for the inertia between changes in global mean temperature and the stock of atmospheric carbon, the optimal price of carbon may follow an inverse U-shaped path and grows more slowly than the Hotelling path (Lemoine and Rudik 2017). Combining the two approach by maximising welfare net of global warming subject to the cap on peak warming or equivalently subject to cumulative emissions being less than the safe carbon budget gives a higher price of carbon than the unconstrained welfare maximisation which grows at a rate somewhere in between the interest rate and the rate of economic growth (van der Ploeg 2017).
Performance of the simple rules
The simple rules predict the fully fledged IAM outcomes in terms of cumulative emissions and peak temperature well. They also predict the deleterious effects of policy inaction
Scenario | Parameters | Optimal carbon budget | Peak temperature | Initial price | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
RTI (%) | IIA | g (%) | SDR (%) | Full IAM (GtC) | Toy IAM (GtC) | Full IAM (°C) | Toy IAM (°C) | Full IAM ($/tC) | TOY IAM ($/tC) | |
Conventional (2 × 2 × 2) | 2 | 2 | 2 | 6 | 1,307 | 1293 | 3.06 | 3.07 | 20 | 12 |
Baseline (Nordhaus) | 1.5 | 1.45 | 2 | 4.4 | 979 | 1025 | 2.73 | 2.78 | 29 | 27 |
Lower discounting | 0.1 | 1.45 | 2 | 3 | 569 | 525 | 2.24 | 2.16 | 81 | 95 |
Lower IIA | 1.5 | 1 | 2 | 3.5 | 759 | 748 | 2.47 | 2.45 | 51 | 55 |
Lower trend growth | 1.5 | 1.45 | 1 | 3 | 805 | 820 | 2.53 | 2.54 | 37 | 38 |
Business-as-usual | Full IAM: cumulative emissions 2250–2300 GtC. Peak temperature 3.89 °C Toy IAM: cumulative emissions 2230–2275 GtC. Peak temperature 3.84 °C |
Our toy IAM performs remarkably well, despite being based on a simple two-box carbon cycle, and adapts accurately to changes in ethical judgement and technological progress (cf. Rezai and van der Ploeg 2016). Cumulative fossil use differs by at most 8%, peak temperature by 0.08 °C, and the initial optimal carbon price by 14 $/tC.9 The transition times are also predicted well by the simple rules (e.g. for the baseline 55 and 56 years for the IAM and for the simple rule, respectively. The social optimum avoids the peak temperatures of around 3.9 °C by locking up much more fossil fuel than the average 2250 GtC burnt under BAU and by transitioning to the carbon-free era in 56 years instead of the end of the century.
Carbon capture and sequestration as backstop
Allen et al. 2009 have argued that there should be a mandate that ensures all carbon emissions above the budget compatible with 2 °C global warming should be captured and sequestrated. Allen (2016) further argued that considerations for the near-term mitigation efforts induced by pricing carbon should be disregarded for long-term impacts of the carbon price for sequestration efforts once the optimal carbon budget will have been reached. Although this plea resonates, a simple cap is not necessarily an efficient strategy. It is more efficient to price carbon as this offers a direct incentive to capture and sequester carbon (as well as to make renewable energy more attractive to use and develop and to phase out fossil fuel more quickly). Furthermore, a price for carbon allows trading to promote the least costly cuts in carbon emissions. It avoids the government “picking winners” and instead promotes development of a wide variety of renewable energy sources including carbon capture and sequestration (CCS). This is important as CCS will, like many other potential new sources of renewable energy, be at most a partial solution to the climate challenge. But CCS faces particular challenges: huge capital investments, environmental hazards, and ugly NIMBY politics. Also, as CCS requires lots of space, it is difficult to scale up as costs rise as space is used up. Abatement with CCS (e.g. new coal, coal retrofit, industrial) is still one of the more expensive forms of abatement. Analytically, the cost of fossil fuel with CCS equals \( E(t)={E}_0{\left(1-{r}_E\right)}^t{\left({S}_0/S(t)\right)}^{e_1} \) per ton of carbon plus the marginal cost of abating one ton of carbon, say A. This is indicated by the upward-sloping dotted black line in Fig. 1. It follows that, like fossil fuel on its own, the cost of CCS rises as reserves are depleted. It thus only becomes attractive for the market when the marginal cost of abatement falls below the carbon price. This happens once GDP and the carbon price have risen far enough or when new technology has diminished the cost of CCS sufficiently, but working against this is that once CCS is scaled up, space becomes ever more costly. Given these cost developments, CCS is likely to be dominated by various forms of renewable energy in the market. Forcing it on the market by mandating it is thus an inefficient way to achieve climate objectives and one would hope one does not have to resort to this once it is too late to rely on conventional, more cost-effective climate policies to curb emissions.
Conclusion
Our assessment of how the optimal carbon price and stranded assets interact with economic growth, renewable energy technology, fossil fuel scarcity, ethical considerations, and fundamental geophysical parameters is transparent and gives easy-to-understand simple rules that perform well in large-scale IAMs. These rules are transparent and robust and in this sense more useful than a discretionary time path of optimal climate policies usually obtained from IAMs. We hope that our back-on-the-envelope framework allows climate scientists not actively engaged in economic modelling to understand the critical assumptions driving the social cost and price of carbon, untapped fossil fuel and the time to reach the carbon-free era in terms of ethical considerations and expected economic growth and cost reductions in renewable energy. In our framework, exogenous improvements in energy efficiency do not affect the optimal price of carbon, but do delay the transition time to the carbon-free era somewhat and provided technical progress in renewable energies or the rate of economic growth are strong enough also depress cumulative emissions and peak global warming significantly.
Our results suggest that the global warming damages estimated and ethical assumptions chosen by economists are likely to lead to global warming that exceeds the 2 °C target. To ensure that global warming always stays below 2 °C, the carbon price must be raised above what conventional economic damages tell us to do and more fossil fuel must be locked up. In recent estimates of the non-climate-related health benefits of abandoning fossil fuels (e.g. Parry et al. 2014; Thompson et al. 2014; West et al. 2013; Ščasný et al. 2015), the effects of uncertainty about the steepness of climate damages (Crost and Traeger 2014) and the potential of multiple abrupt disruptions in the climate system (Cai et al. 2016; Lemoine and Traeger 2016) provide ample reasons for raising the carbon price.
Footnotes
- 1.
Allen (2016) also offers a simple framework for analysing the drivers of peak warming and the optimal carbon budget in a consumer-maximising world, but focuses on the need for carbon capture and sequestration rather than the transition to renewable energy and does not discuss the ethical drivers of climate policy or the optimal timing of the transition to the carbon-free era.
- 2.
A three-box model leads to a slightly better short-run temperature response (Gerlagh and Liski 2017).
- 3.
Most IAMs assume damages as a fraction of GDP to be convex in temperature while temperature is usually concave (logarithmic) in atmospheric concentrations so that the overall effect gives a near linear relationship.
- 4.
Gollier (2013) uses SDR = RTI + IIA × g − 0.5 RRA × PRU × σ2, where PRU = 1 + IIA.
- 5.
- 6.
- 7.
- 8.
With uncertainty about future consumption growth, the SDR in the baseline is cut by 0.14% per annum. This curbs the carbon budget and peak global warming by only 36 GtC and 0.04 °C, respectively.
- 9.
Notes
Acknowledgements
An earlier version of this paper was presented as a keynote at the ECOCOP Workshop, Prague, 3–4 November 2016. We are grateful to the helpful and constructive comments of Milan Ščasný and two anonymous referees. Van der Ploeg is grateful for support from FP7-IDEAS-ERC grant no. 269788. Rezai is grateful for support from the Austrian Science Fund (FWF): J 3633 and OeNB Anniversary Fund (grant no. 15330).
References
- Allen, M. R. (2016). Drivers of peak warming in a consumption-maximizing world. Nature Climate Change, 6(7), 684–686. https://doi.org/10.1038/nclimate2977.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Allen, M. R., Frame, D. J., Huntingford, C., Jones, C. D., Lowe, J. A., Meinshausen, M., & Meinshausen, N. (2009). Warming caused by cumulative emissions towards the trillionth tonne. Nature, 458(7242), 1163–1166. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature08019.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bauer, N., Bosetti, V., Hamdi-Cheriff, M., Kitous, A., McCollum, D., Mjean, A., Rao, S., Turton, H., Paroussos, L., Ashina, S., Calvin, K., Wada, K., & van Vuuren, D. (2015). CO2 emission mitigation and fossil fuel markets: dynamic and international aspects of climate policy. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 90(A), 243–256. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2013.09.009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cai, Y., Judd, K., Lenton, T. M., & Lontzek, T. S. (2016). Risk of multiple climate tipping points should trigger a rapid reduction in CO2 emissions. Nature Climate Change, 6(5), 520–525. https://doi.org/10.1038/nclimate2964.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Carbon Tracker & Grantham Research Institute. (2013). Unburnable carbon 2013: wasted capital and stranded assets. London: Grantham Research Institute.Google Scholar
- Crost, B., & Traeger, C. (2014). Optimal CO2 mitigation under damage risk valuation. Nature Climate Change, 4(7), 631–636. https://doi.org/10.1038/nclimate2249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Dietz, S., Gollier, C., & Kessler, L. (2017). The climate beta. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2017.07.005.
- Epstein, L. G., & Zin, S. E. (1989). Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: a theoretical framework. Econometrica, 57(4), 937–969. https://doi.org/10.2307/1913778.MathSciNetCrossRefMATHGoogle Scholar
- Gerlagh, R., & Liski, M. (2017). Consistent climate policies. Journal of the European Economic Association. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeea/jvx010.
- Gollier, C. (2013). Pricing the planet’s future. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
- Golosov, M., Hassler, J., Krusell, P., & Tsyvinski, A. (2014). Optimal taxes and fossil fuel in general equilibrium. Econometrica, 82(1), 41–88.MathSciNetCrossRefMATHGoogle Scholar
- Hassler, J., Krusell, P., & Olovsson, C. (2012). Energy-saving technical change. NBER Working Paper 18456. Cambridge: Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kimball, M. S. (1990). Precautionary saving in the small and in the large. Econometrica, 58(1), 53–73. https://doi.org/10.2307/2938334.MathSciNetCrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Lemoine, D., & Rudik, I. (2017). Steering the climate system: using inertia to lower the cost of policy. American Economic Review, 107(10), 2947–2957. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20150986.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Lemoine, D., & Traeger, C. (2016). Economics of tipping the climate dominoes. Nature Climate Change, 6(5), 514–519. https://doi.org/10.1038/nclimate2902.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- McGlade, C., & Ekins, P. (2015). The geographical distribution of fossil fuels unused when limiting global warming to 2°C. Nature, 517(7533), 187–190. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature14016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Meinshausen, M., Meinshausen, N., Hare, W., Raper, S. C. B., Frieler, K., Knutti, R., Frame, D. J., & Allen, M. R. (2009). Greenhouse emission targets for limiting global warming to 2°C. Nature, 458(7242), 1158–1162. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature08017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Metcalf, G. E., & Stock, J. (2015). The role of integrated assessment models in climate policy: a user’s guide and assessment, Discussion Paper 2015–68. Cambridge: Mass.: Harvard Project on Climate Agreements.Google Scholar
- Nordhaus, W. (1982). How fast should we graze the global commons? American Economic Review, 72(2), 242–246.Google Scholar
- Nordhaus, W. (2007). A review of the Stern Review on the economics of climate change. Journal of Economic Literature, 45(3), 686–702. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.45.3.686.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Nordhaus, W. (2008). A question of balance—weighing the options on global warming policies. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
- Nordhaus, W. (2014). Estimates of the social cost of carbon: concepts and results from the DICE-2013R model and alternative approaches. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, 1(1/2), 273–312. https://doi.org/10.1086/676035.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Parry, I., Veung, C., & Heine, D. (2014). How much carbon pricing is in countries’ own interests? The critical role of co-benefits, CESifo Working Paper 5015. Munich: CESifo.Google Scholar
- Pindyck, R. S. (2013). Climate change policy: what do the models tell us? Journal of Economic Literature, 51(3), 860–872. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.51.3.860.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Pindyck, R. S. (2017). The use and misuse of models for climate policy. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 11(1), 100–114. https://doi.org/10.1093/reep/rew012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Rezai, A., & van der Ploeg, F. (2016). Intergenerational inequality aversion, growth, and the role of damages: Occam’s rule for the global carbon tax. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, 3(2), 493–522. https://doi.org/10.1086/686294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ščasný, M., Massetti, E., Melichar, J., & Carrara, S. (2015). Quantifying the ancillary benefits of the representative concentration pathways on air quality in Europe. Environmental & Resource Economics, 62(2), 383–415. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-015-9969-y.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Stern, N. H. (2007). The economics of climate change: the Stern Review. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511817434.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Stern, N. (2016). Economics: current climate models are grossly misleading. Nature, 530(7591), 407–409. https://doi.org/10.1038/530407a.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Thompson, T. M., Rausch, S., Saari, R. K., & Selin, N. E. (2014). A systems approach to evaluating the air quality co-benefits of US carbon policies. Nature Climate Change, 4(10), 917–923. https://doi.org/10.1038/nclimate2342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Tol, R. S. J. (2013). Targets for global climate policy: an overview. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 37(5), 911–928. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2013.01.001.MathSciNetCrossRefGoogle Scholar
- van der Ploeg, F. (2017). The safe carbon budget, CESifo Working Paper 6620. Munich: CESifo.Google Scholar
- Weitzman, M. L. (2007). A review of the Stern Review on the economics of climate change. Journal of Economic Literature, 45(3), 703–724. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.45.3.703.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- West, J. J., Smith, S. J., Silva, R. A., Naik, V., Zhang, Y., Adelman, Z., Fry, M. M., Anenberg, S., Horowitz, L. W., & Lamarque, J.-F. (2013). Co-benefits of global greenhouse gas mitigation for future air quality and human health. Nature Climate Change, 3(10), 885–889. https://doi.org/10.1038/nclimate2009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copyright information
Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.